Mathematics

Where do Adjunctions come from?

Category theory has foundational importance because it provides conceptual lenses to characterize what is important and universal in mathematics—with adjunction seeming to be the primary lens. Our topic is a theory showing “where adjoints come from”.

Born Again! The Born Rule as a Feature of Superposition

Where does the Born Rule come from? We ask: “What is the simplest extension of probability theory where the Born rule appears”? This is answered by introducing “superposition events” in addition to the usual discrete events.

The heteromorphic approach to adjunctions: theory and history

In this paper, the history and theory of adjoint functors is investigated. Where do adjoint functors come from mathematically, and how did the concept develop historically?

A new logical measure for quantum information

Logical entropy is compared and contrasted with the usual notion of Shannon entropy. Then a semi-algorithmic procedure (from the mathematical folklore) is used to translate the notion of logical entropy at the set level to the corresponding notion of quantum logical entropy at the (Hilbert) vector space level.

A Fundamental Duality in the Mathematical and Natural Sciences

This is an essay in what might be called “mathematical metaphysics.” There is a fundamental duality that runs through mathematics and the natural sciences, from logic to biology.

A Talk on Logic and Information in Krakow

  Click here to download the slides.

Keiretsu, Proportional Representation, and Input-Output Theory

This is Chapter 9 in my book: Ellerman, David. 1995. Intellectual Trespassing as a Way of Life: Essays in Philosophy, Economics, and Mathematics. Lanham MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

This essay grew out of an attempt to model mathematically the possible cross-ownership arrangements that might arise between privatizing firms in the former Yugoslavia [see Ellerman 1991].  The cross-ownership arrangements resemble the groups of Japanese companies called keiretsu.  There is cross ownership between the companies in the group as well as some ownership outside the group that is traded on the stock market.  In spite of the partial outside ownership, the keiretsu often behave as “self-owning” groups.  If firm A owns shares in B, then the management in A usually signs over its proxy on shares in B to the management in firm B.  And the management in B does likewise with respect to the managers in A.  Thus within certain constraints, each firm can act like a “self-owning” firm, not totally unlike the self-managing firms of the former Yugoslavia. 

Parallel Addition, Series-Parallel Duality, and Financial Mathematics

This is Chapter 12 in my book: Ellerman, David. 1995. Intellectual Trespassing as a Way of Life: Essays in Philosophy, Economics, and Mathematics. Lanham MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

Valuation rings: A better algebraic treatment of Boolean algebras

This is Chapter 11 in my book: Ellerman, David. 1995. Intellectual Trespassing as a Way of Life: Essays in Philosophy, Economics, and Mathematics. Lanham MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

Finding the Markets in the Math: Arbitrage and Optimization Theory

This is Chapter 10 from my book: Ellerman, David. 1995. Intellectual Trespassing as a Way of Life: Essays in Philosophy, Economics, and Mathematics. Lanham MD: Rowman & Littlefield.

One of the fundamental insights of mainstream neoclassical economics is the connection between competitive market prices and the Lagrange multipliers of optimization theory in mathematics.  Yet this insight has not been well developed.  In the standard theory of markets, competitive prices result from the equilibrium of supply and demand schedules.  But in a constrained optimization problem, there seems to be no mathematical version of supply and demand functions so that the Lagrange multipliers would be seen as equilibrium prices.  How can one “find the markets in the math” so that Lagrange multipliers will emerge as equilibrium market prices?